|
|
|
|
FISCAL
INCENTIVES ARE INDISPENSABLE PREREQUISITES
FOR THE DEVELOPMENT OF EMPLOYEE
SHARE OWNERSHIP
- ALL REACTIONS
Worldwide
practical evidence and a wide range of academic
research support the view that a proper legal
environment and the provision of suitable
fiscal incentives are indispensable prerequisites
for any policy truly aiming the development
of employee share ownership. Experts and organizations
worldwide are invited to react.
|
ALL
REACTIONS FROM
EXPERTS AND ORGANIZATIONS
WORLDWIDE
|
|
POSITIVE
REACTIONS
John Hoffmire Director, Center
on Business and Poverty, Wisconsin School of
Business, UW-Madison (USA); Philippe Dancot,
Former Head of International Employee Share
Plans - Saint-Gobain (France); Božo Lednik,
DEZAP Slovenian Association for Employee Ownership
(Slovenia); Janos Lukacs, Share Participation
Foundation (Hungary); Guido Antolini, DirCredito
(Italy); Debory Eres (France); Corey Rosen,
Fondateur, National Center for Employee Ownership
(USA); August Van Put, HBK Bank (Belgium); Myriam
Biot, Founder member of the EFES (Belgium);
Gérard Gruet-Masson, Fondact (France);
Javier San José, Miembro del Comité Ejecutivo
de EFES, Confederación Empresarial de Sociedades
Laborales de España (Spain); Voestalpine Employee
Participation (Austria); Pascale Nieuwland,
SNPI (The Netherlands); Emanuele di Francesco,
University of Utrecht (The Netherlands); Jan
Procházka, President, KSLP - The Czech Society
for Employee Participation |
All
reactions as a PDF
(last
update: 20.9.2014)
|
John Hoffmire Director, Center on Business
and Poverty, Wisconsin School of Business, UW-Madison
(USA)
Please find below my statement in support of
fiscal incentives for employee ownership. Various
positions are held by opinion leaders about
the role of the state in economic development.
Along a spectrum of acceptance, some opinions
are widely shared. For example, many accept
that governments should be involved in influencing
interest rates. On the other end of the spectrum,
there is less and less support for governments
wholly owning manufacturing companies. Along
this spectrum, there is fairly strong acceptance
of forms of employee ownership which diversify
employees' retirement holdings away from only
having employer securities in the basket of
assets that will protect employees as they age.
There are several reasons for this acceptance:
1) stock option plans and other similar schemes
have been adopted around the world as a means
to effectively incentivize managers and workforces;
2) world opinion has shifted toward a belief
that the ratio of wealth that should be owned
by the wealthiest should be lower, not higher;
3) diverse successful means have been developed
to encourage employee ownership in many different
cultural and legal frameworks. As one examines
the most successful models of encouraging greater
employee ownership, there is little doubt that
nations which give tax advantages to support
employee ownership are seeing faster growth
in employee holdings. The United States is the
prime example where greater state support has
led to first rapid growth of ESOPs and now sustained
replacement of ESOP companies which move away
from employee ownership. That is, in the present
environment, in most years, for each company
that moves away from employee ownership there
is a new ESOP. In sum, for reasons of greater
productivity and greater creation of equal economic
opportunity, the world is seeing growth in employee
share ownership. This growth would not take
place at the same rates without state support.
|
|
Philippe Dancot, Former Head of International
Employee Share Plans - Saint-Gobain (France)
C'est un euphémisme de dire que les incitants
fiscaux sont nécessaires, ils sont indispensables
au développement de l'actionnariat salarié.
J'en veux pour preuve le succès d'un même plan
(dans ce cas de figure, celui de Saint-Gobain)
présenté chaque année dans près de 50 pays:
le taux de participation moyen est supérieur
à 50% en France, inférieur à 10% en zone euro
et inférieur à 5% hors Europe. Trois facteurs
essentiels pour le succès des souscriptions:
les incitants fiscaux (très généreux en France),
l'absence de risque de change, et la dynamique
d'évolution du cours de l'action pendant la
période de souscription ( ce dernier facteur
étant de nature purement psychologique). Par
ailleurs, il est important que ces incitants
soient contre-balancés par une obligation de
blocage des actions (par exemple 5 ans ou plus),
ce qui crée une véritable épargne à long terme.
Ceci est d'autant plus important que le financement
des retraites devient un souci public majeur.
Étant moi-même retraité, je mesure l'intérêt
et le confort qu'une telle épargne peut constituer.
Amicalement. |
|
Božo
Lednik, DEZAP Slovenian Association for Employee
Ownership (Slovenia)
I ask you kindly for your permision to translate,
make a sumary and publicate The Manifesto in
Slovenian review "Industrijska demokracija".
With kind regards. |
|
Debory
Eres (France)
Nous sommes tout à fait d'accord avec la position
de la Fédération Européenne de l'Actionnariat
Salarié et la félicitons pour son travail formidable
au service de la promotion et au développement
de l'actionnariat salarié partout en Europe.
Si la France est championne d'Europe de l'actionnariat
salarié "démocratique" (47,2% de salariés actionnaires
en 2013 contre 28% en Europe), c'est parce que
notre pays a une longue tradition de réconciliation
du capital et du travail initiée par Général
de Gaulle quand il a créé l'intéressement et
la participation. Mais c'est aussi grâce à une
fiscalité incitative qui ne taxe pas au moment
de la souscription et quasiment pas à la sortie
du plan, grâce à la non fiscalisation des dividendes
dans le PEE, grâce au FCPE qui permet d'intermédier
et donc de simplifier la relation avec les salariés
actionnaires. Le développement de l'actionnariat
salarié passe, sans aucun doute, par des incitations
fiscales, par la création de dispositifs souples,
par la simplification et le renforcement des
mécanismes existants. |
|
Corey Rosen,
Founder, National Center for Employee Ownership
(USA)
(The
NCEO is a nonprofit membership and research
organization that was founded in 1981 to provide
most objective and reliable information on
broad-based employee ownership. It is widely
considered the leading source of information
on employee ownership in the U.S. and worldwide.)
Here
are my comments. Good luck with your efforts.
Are
Tax Incentives Necessary for Broad Employee
Ownership?
The
report Employee’s Financial Participation
in Companies’ Policies argues that fiscal
incentives (both tax and non-tax) appear to
be related to the wider adoption of employee
ownership plans, but may not be a prerequisite
for these plans. It is inarguable that they
are not a prerequisite — companies may set
up plans even without any incentives out of
a philosophical commitment to the idea. This
is perhaps best exemplified by the Mondragon
Group in Spain. Based on our work over the
past 33 years studying employee ownership
in the U.S. and in other countries, however,
it is clear that for employee ownership to
play a substantial role in the economy, tax
incentives are very much needed.
Different
Modes of Employee Ownership and Their Impact
on Employees and Companies
Before
answering the question of the importance of
fiscal incentives, we need to look at what
kind of employee ownership countries want
to encourage and what the consequences of
different forms of ownership are.
In
Europe, the most common form of employee ownership
is the employee purchase plan in publicly
traded companies. These plans often offer
some discount and many countries provide some
form of tax incentive to the employee. Employees
hold shares individually for varying amounts
of time. These plans typically result in small
percentages of ownership (5% or less) held
by employees and, most often, less than a
majority of employees buying shares, especially
lower income employees. There is no research
to indicate that these companies show improved
financial performance as a result of employee
ownership. The research on employee ownership
in the U.S., where employee ownership is most
prevalent, shows that employee ownership improves
performance only when employees own a more
substantial share of the company, ownership
is broadly distributed, and companies have
cultures of high information sharing and shared
participation in decisions. Providing incentives
for employee share purchases may be useful
to improve employee financial well being,
however.
In
France and the United Kingdom, and especially
the U.S., there are also plans that hold shares
collectively for employees in some kind of
trust. The employees usually do not get the
stock until after they leave. The plans tend
to be broadly inclusive and are funded by
the employer not the employee. These plans
have a much higher potential for effecting
corporate performance and tend to have a much
larger impact on employee asset accumulation.
In the typical U.S. ESOP, for instance, plans
own at least 30% and often 100% of the company,
companies contribute 6% to 8% of pay per year
to the plan (this is not in lieu of, but in
addition to pay) or more, and employees end
up with about 2.5 times the retirement assets
on companies without employee ownership. These
companies also grow about 2.5% per year faster
and lay people off at one-third to one-fourth
the rate of non-ESOP companies.
The
difficulty with the typical models that do
not have some kind of share pooling mechanism,
such as an ESOP trust in the U.S., is that
relying on employees to purchase shares, even
if they are getting a match or a discount,
almost always means that:
·
A majority of eligible employees will
usually not participate even when there are
incentives. Studies consistently show that
people tend to overvalue current income versus
future rewards and overvalue risk. Employees
often live "paycheck to paycheck,"
making participation in a share purchase plan
challenging.
· Among
those who do participate, the amounts set
aside will be skewed towards those higher
paid employees with more disposable income.
· Participants
will usually sell their shares when they can.
While they may also buy new shares, their
holdings will not aggregate over time, as
they do in a trust where the shares are usually
accumulated until departure. This approach
gives people a much larger stake as owners.
· Employees,
as a group, will always be minority owners,
usually 10% or less. That creates far fewer
incentives for managers to set up extensive
employee ownership culture models, as would
be the case where employee ownership is long-term
and substantial. Yet we know that employee
ownership only produces substantial performance
improvements when combined with cultures that
stress employee involvement in day-to-day
work decisions.
What
Kinds of Fiscal Incentives Make Sense?
Because
of all this, we believe that countries that
want sustained, substantial, and broad employee
ownership in companies need to provide ways
that the ownership is not based on employees
making decisions to use current income to
buy shares, but rather on company contributions
with tax benefits for the companies and/or
sellers to employee ownership plans doing
this. The ownership plan also needs to pool
ownership and allocate shares to individual
employees during their tenure with the firm.
These
tax incentives should be both at the corporate
and individual level. Because the most equitable
and deep plans are necessarily company funded,
owners need incentives to set them up. This
is especially true for closely held companies
where the goal is to use a company-funded
employee ownership plan to buy out the owners.
Absent tax incentives, owners will sell to
someone else. There were virtually no plans
like this in the U.S. until tax incentives
for ESOPs were created. Now there are over
7,000 ESOPs, mostly used for this purpose,
employing millions of people. ESOP tax incentives
amount to only about $2 billion/year, but,
based on a National Center for Employee Ownership
analysis, save over $8 billion per year in
federal unemployment costs alone (because
ESOP companies pay people off so much less
often). By contrast, states spend over $80
billion in tax incentives to encourage companies
to move from one place to another with no
net job gain. The U.K. is now moving to create
a very similar structure with similar tax
benefits.
It
is also important that U.S. and U.K. that
while the incentives focus on the employer,
contributions do not trigger any current taxation
on employees. Tax is deferred until income
is realized. Doing anything else makes employee
ownership more punitive than rewarding, at
least in the short-term.
In
public companies, tax incentives can encourage
contributions as well. But the economic and
political reality is that shareholders and
often governments are reluctant to shoulder
the costs of significant annual company contributions
for shares. Employee purchase models are a
much easier sell. While these models are imperfect
for the reasons we have stated, absent incentives
for employees to help offset their risk aversion
and current income preference, employee ownership
will necessarily be a limited phenomenon except
in certain idiosyncratic companies with very
strong ownership cultures. In the U.S, employee
stock purchase plans typically offer employees
an essentially guaranteed 5% to 15% annual
return, and often more, with no risk but rates
of participation in these plans, which require
setting aside money on a regular basis out
of salaries, are still only about one-third
the work force.
If
governments want to encourage broader and
deeper employee ownership plans in these countries,
they should consider tax benefits to the employer
for setting up plans that involve most or
all employees meeting certain eligibility
requirements. The special tax incentives would
only become effective if a certain number
of employees participated.
A
more aggressive approach might provide incentives
for plans such as that at Schneider Electric,
which has a very high-take up rate. Employees
can borrow money to buy shares. The loans
come from a bank, but the arrangements were
made by the company, but they are non-recourse
to employees if the stock does not increase
enough to repay the loan. For each share an
employee buys, nine more are purchased on
the employee's behalf. At the end of the plan's
holding period, the employee receives shares
having a value equal to the original share
purchased plus an amount equal to 5.5 times
the increase in value (if any) of that share.
Thus, for the price of one share, the employee
receives the value of that share plus 55%
of the gain (if any) on all ten shares. The
bank receives the remainder of the gain. This
gives the employee the chance to make a substantial
gain with a relatively small risk, since the
bank does not have recourse to the employees.
The lender hedges its risk through buying
puts and calls on Schneider stock.
Conclusion
Fiscal
incentive policies need to be crafted with
a view towards what role a country hopes employee
ownership will play. If the goal is to provide
employees, mostly in listed firms, with a
tax-favored way to accumulate assets, then
tax incentives for employees to offset their
risk aversion and time preference may be enough.
But if the goal is to make employee ownership
another model for corporate organization,
then fiscal policy needs to provide substantial
incentives to employers and deferred taxation
for employees. The research in the U.S. and
U.K. have shown clearly that the benefits
are worth the cost. For a detailed review
of U/S. research, see the article Research
on Employee Ownership, Corporate Performance,
and Employee Communication on the web
site of the National Center for Employee Ownership.
|
|
Guido
Antolini, DirCredito (Italia)
We are going
to translate the Manifesto also in Italian,
as a fundamental side tool for the audition
we asked for to the Italian Senate, in the occasion
of the law proposition about workers' participation.
|
|
August
Van Put, HBK Bank (Belgium)
Mes félicitations
pour le nouveau Manifeste. Il m'est impossible
de le dire mieux ou de le compléter. L'argumentation
est complète et parfaite. Merci pour le travail
fait avec la FEAS. |
|
Gérard
Gruet-Masson, Fondact (France)
Il serait bon
de compléter ce mémo par quelques données économiques
supplémentaires. On peut partir du constat que
0,1 point de croissance supplémentaire, c'est
2Mds€ de rentrées fiscales supplémentaires.
Comment faire de l'actionnariat et de l'intéressement
un levier de croissance. Il y a des liens et
des chiffrages à mettre en évidence. C'est le
point essentiel qui intéresse nos gouvernants.
Lorsque cette démonstration est faite, il est
plus facile de plaider pour des incitations
fiscales. Amitiés. |
|
Javier
San José, Miembro del Comité Ejecutivo de EFES,
Confederación Empresarial de Sociedades Laborales
de España (Spain)
Je suis d´accord
avec la proposition de la EFES sur les incitants
fiscaux. Ils sont une condition totalement indispensable
pour le développement de la participation des
salariés. Un des problèmes pour quoi il n'y
a pas plus de sociedades laborales est
l'inexistence d'incitants fiscaux. |
|
Robert
Scallon, Treasurer, FAST - Federation of Associations
of Staff Shareholders of Thales
I agree that
fiscal incentives are indispensable to encourage
the spread of employee share-ownership throughout
Europe. This is particularly true at the time
of investment. The counterpart for governments
is that such incentives generate GDP growth
and that such employee share-ownership improves
company performance, both leading to greater
tax revenues over time. |
|
Voestalpine
Employee Participation (Austria)
The voestalpine
Employee Participation is present internationally
in several European countries. Our experience
shows that the participation rate in the different
countries is mainly dependent on the varying
the incentive systems available in the respective
countries. Through the development of such tax
incentive systems, employee motivation and identification
increase. Employees, as shareholders, are also
an important factor with respect to securing
the future of the company site. |
|
Pascale
Nieuwland, SNPI (The Netherlands)
First of all.
It is very good to make a new manifest. The
idea is good. But the way it is composed we
are not sure if it has the effect EFES is looking
for. Yes, we from SNPI agree that fiscal incentives
do help a lot with the promotion and development
of ESO. But I am afraid that focusing too much
on these fiscal incentives is not the way to
start a dialogue with governments and ministries.
Governments could easily just say no to the
report and then there is nothing more to discuss.
It does not start a dialogue. The current title
is just one of the many things that could be
done. We would be more happy with a phrase like:
Governmental support is indispensable prerequisites
for the development of employee share ownership.
Governments should facilitate ESO more, and
fiscal incentives is just one way to do this.
Any government could do more. Information can
be improved in most countries. Where to find
the right information. Models, examples you
name it. And many countries lack a governmental
statement on this topic. Furthermore when reading
the manifest, we notice that you focus on Jens
Lowitsch a lot. Why is there so much focus on
Jens Lowitsch and why is it not more an independent
manifest for the promotion of ESO? I am curious
what others think of this? As said, good to
have a manifest. But when being honest, we are
not so convinced about the title and content
of the manifest. It is difficult to see how
we are able to use it here in The Netherlands.
Maybe when hearing the responds of the others,
I will get some ideas. |
|
Emanuele
di Francesco, University of Utrecht (The Netherlands)
This is my
reaction to the EFES manifesto. The economic
arena, where economic activity takes place,
is shaped by two fundamental elements: institutions
and incentives. Built on a mutual relationship,
they set the rules of the game and define the
spectrum and nature of activities that economic
actors will undertake. Doing so, in practice,
they create the economic environment. From this,
it directly follows the corollary that favorable
institutions and incentives are per se necessary
prerequisites for productive and economic performant
activities. Entering in the specific case, I
believe that fiscal incentives (the most direct
- if not the only - way through which States
incentivize economic activity) are necessary
for a long-termed and sustainable broad-based
ownership. In that they give the right incentive
to create a more productive and equal world,
with greater social cohesion and participation.
The academic research is conclusive on the issue
and all the results point to corporate performance
enhancements due to employee share ownership
programs, in specified conditions. Now, I believe,
has come the time to educate and inform regarding
employee share ownership, to create the favorable
institutional setting, and to assist consistently
the firms, especially the SMEs, in their implementation
phase of the programme. Thus, I absolutely stand
together with the EFES in the attempt to promote
a favorable political and economical environment
for the evolution of a more wealth-decentralized
and equal society. |
|
Jan Procházka,
President, KSLP - The Czech Society for Employee
Participation
Our society
agree with the fact that fiscal incentives are
indispensable prerequisites for the development
of employee share ownership. The international
experience is the proof that the extent of employee
participation in different countries depends
mainly on the quality and significance of incentive
systems available in the respective countries.
Development of fiscal incentive systems so creates
the best conditions for employee involvement
and consequently also incentive to promote theirs
companies, helping to increase the company performance.
Employee participation is a possible source
of extra income that can supplement individual
savings plan, or can act as a secondary source
of income next to any retirement savings plan
carried out by the state and by employers. Higher
attention to and practical promotion of such
fiscal incentives would be also the promotion
of our effort to increase employee participation
in our country. |
|
|
|
For
information and contact
EFES - EUROPEAN
FEDERATION OF EMPLOYEE SHARE OWNERSHIP
FEAS - FEDERATION EUROPEENNE DE L'ACTIONNARIAT SALARIE
Avenue Voltaire 135, B-1030 Brussels
Tel: +32 (0)2 242 64 30 - Fax: +32 (0)2 808 30 33
E-mail: efes@efesonline.org
Web site: www.efesonline.org
EFES' objective is to act as the umbrella organization
of employee owners, companies and all persons, trade
unions, experts, researchers, institutions looking
to promote employee share ownership and participation
in Europe.
| | |